MENU

《经济学人》增税和台风后日本 GDP 急剧下降

2020 年 02 月 22 日 • 经济学人,经济金融

本期经济学人杂志【经济金融】板块下题为《Japan’s GDP shrinks dramatically after a tax rise and a typhoon》的文章认为安倍政府去年十月份的增加消费税的举措是一种主动失误,并且这种经济政策上的失误安倍已经是第二次犯了。

The Economist, February 22nd-28th 2020.

2019 年 10 月 1 日起日本将消费税从 8% 提高到 10%,当年第四季度的年化经济增长率环比下跌了 6.3%。安倍政府在 2014 年第一次增加消费税后,经济也出现过突然的收缩。

文章认为日本政府眼下并不急需用钱,这是安倍政府在财政政策上的又一次主动失误。尽管当前日本的债务接近 GDP 的 240%,但由于国债利率接近 0,日本政府的借贷成本非常低。况且当前日本的通胀率仅为 0.8%(目标是 2%),居民私人支出不足,安倍政府提高消费税的行为实在令人费解。

虽然之后出台的一些抵消措施起到了一些缓解作用,但随之而来的台风又使情况恶化。2019 年 10 月初的超强台风海贝思给日本造成了很大的损失,包括约 100 人死亡。台风过后,企业资本支出下降。

最近爆发的新冠肺炎疫情更是让日本经济雪上加霜。日本已紧密融入世界制造业供应链体系中,中国工厂停工会打乱日本企业生产计划。原本日本还指望通过今年 7 月份的东京奥运会提振国民情绪和刺激支出,但新冠肺炎让这种愿望蒙上了阴影。

面对种种不利,文章认为日本央行(BOJ)比较为难,进一步货币宽松的难度较大。一方面,自 2016 年后日本央行就让一些银行储备的利率降到 -0.1% 的负利率,但通胀仍低于预期目标;另一方面,负利率不受银行、保险机构和储户们的欢迎。

增税、台风和肺炎疫情虽然压制了需求,但仍对价格上行有助推作用,这样的话日本央行就只能推迟可能的货币宽松政策了。文章最后认为,日本最终可能会走出“滞胀”,但在这之前必须要经历一段痛苦的“滞胀”过程。
20200222_WOC197.png

Japan’s GDP shrinks dramatically after a tax rise and a typhoon

Fiscal, natural, viral
Japan’s GDP shrinks dramatically after a tax rise and a typhoon

ECONOMISTS STILL argue about the merits of Abenomics, the experimental mix of policies introduced by Japan’s prime minister, Abe Shinzo, seven years ago, in an effort to chase away deflation and stagnation. But two lessons are beyond debate. Japan’s bond market is remarkably docile despite the government’s towering debt. Japanese households, however, are painfully sensitive to increases in the consumption tax, a broad value-added tax imposed on most of their purchases. After the government raised the tax from 8% to 10% on October 1st, the economy shrank at an annual pace of 6.3% in the fourth quarter of 2019, according to figures released on February 17th (see chart ).

The tax increase was an unforced error. The government faces no immediate need for additional revenue. Despite gross debt nearing 240% of GDP, its borrowing remains absurdly cheap. The yield on a ten-year government bond is stuck at about zero, where the country’s central bank, the Bank of Japan (BoJ), has pegged it since 2016. That peg obliges the BoJ to buy as much government debt as necessary to keep long-term interest rates low. Such determined efforts to stimulate borrowing are needed chiefly because private spending has been weak—too weak, at least, to lift inflation to the BoJ’s target of 2% from the current 0.8%. Thus the consumption-tax rise was doubly strange. It made it even harder for firms to sell goods to Japan’s inhibited consumers, for the sake of reducing the number of bonds Japan’s government sells to a customer who has sworn to bid for them anyway. It was like adding ballast to the waterlogged side of a ship.

The error was foreseeable as well as unforced. A rise in the same tax in 2014 was followed by a similarly dramatic contraction in the economy, undermining the early momentum of Mr Abe’s reflationary push. The government had hoped to avoid a repeat of that experience by sparing food, newspapers and drinks (except alcohol) from the higher rate and by adding various compensatory measures. These included free child care and education for pre-school kids and a “rewards” system giving discounts to customers who make cashless purchases in small shops and convenience stores. These measures may have softened the blow in some ways: consumer spending on non-durable goods fell by less last quarter than it did in the 2014 episode. Unfortunately, these offsetting measures were themselves offset by another aggravating factor: the impact of Typhoon Hagibis, which inundated many towns and killed almost 100 people in October. As a consequence, capital spending by firms shrank even faster than it had after the tax increase six years ago.

The economy’s prospects for recovery are threatened further by the new coronavirus. Covid-19 has already killed one person in Japan; 73 have been infected (not counting hundreds diagnosed on a cruise ship docked in Yokohama, south of Tokyo). Japan is tightly integrated into Asian manufacturing supply chains that will be disrupted by factory shutdowns in China. It has also been counting on the Tokyo Olympics, which start in July, to lift spirits and spending. That happy prospect must now be in doubt. The government has already said that only elite athletes can take part in the Tokyo marathon on March 1st.

Faced with these fiscal, meteorological and viral setbacks, how will policymakers respond? The government has announced a fiscal stimulus worth about $120bn (2.4% of GDP), which will help repair typhoon damage and shield the country from future floods and other disasters. But the money will be spread over more than a year and may not add much to the prior trajectory of spending. The BoJ, for its part, seems largely out of ideas. Inflation has persistently undershot its target, which would call for easier monetary policy. But the BoJ’s tiered system of interest on the reserves that banks deposit with it, with some of them earning a negative rate (-0.1%), is already unpopular with savers, banks and insurance companies. An even lower rate might be counterproductive if it inflicts too much damage on Japan’s financial institutions, which struggle to pass the negative rates on to their own depositors.

A possible solution, proposed by Stefan Angrick of Oxford Economics, a British consultancy, would be for the BoJ to pay positive interest on more reserves, to shore up the banks’ profitability, but even lower rates on the remainder, to help stimulate borrowing. A more sharply tiered system like this helped Switzerland’s central bank cut interest rates to -0.75%.

One twist is that all three of Japan’s recent disasters—the tax increase, the typhoon and the virus—ought to put upward pressure on prices, even as they depress demand. That should prevent any return to outright deflation. But even policymakers desperate to ensure Japan escapes from deflation are unlikely to prefer stagflation. ■

This article appeared in the Asia section of the print edition under the headline"Typhoon, pestilence and tax"

赞助博客

2016~2024 年经济学人高清 PDF 合集
赞助合集
2016~2024 年经济学人高清 PDF 合集
赞助合集